Thursday, 27 August 2009
Market failures vs government failures
In the second part of his address, Stern argued that only a broad and encompassing effort by economists would be able to respond to the two main challenges the world faces today: Climate change and the alleviation of poverty, two goals that, he added, must be tackled jointly. Stern argued that we already own some of the necessary tools to do this. We, economists, just simply forgot them. He added that nevertheless these are just starting points (pigouvian taxes on externalities would not be enough to do the trick) and that the new advances on behavioral economics, institutional economics and theories of justice were the lines to follow.
Some of the final points made by Stern were slightly more vague. He argued that discussion and deliberation are necessary to achieve these objectives. These procedures are of paramount importance if we want a complete shift in preferences and views on individual responsability, in the same way in which decades ago society decided through public debate that driving under the influence of alcohol should be sanctioned. In the meantime, the Economics profession should enlighten such debate with new research primarily focused on market failures rather than on government misdeeds.
You can watch the lecture in full here.
Tuesday, 25 August 2009
Immoral safety?
But there are some situations where the economy is organised so that too little risk is taken. Suppose you have responsibility in an organisation for health and safety, or avoiding accusations of discrimination. If you are judged just on these criteria, and if you can impose regulations on those in the organisation who produce the final product, then why not impose the tightest regulations possible. This will maximise those indicators on which you are judged (e.g. no accidents, or no lawsuits).
But if you try to get rid of all downside risk, there can be no upside benefit. No risks are taken and the organisation stagnates. You see this in some schools, where teachers avoid activities that may involve some risk to children. But then the children will not get the benefits of those activities.
This is a form of moral hazard, perhaps better called immoral safety.
Monday, 24 August 2009
Credit Crunch reading
This youtube video.
At Brown University, there was a "conversation" between Peter Howitt, David Weil and Ross Levine, who discussed the economic situation, the bailout, and the outlook for the future (with paerticular reference to the US). Here's the video, and a short description in the Brown student newspaper.
Robert Skidelsky's recent review in the New York Review of Books of Martin Wolf's book. This is a thoughtful review bringing in nicely the role played by the global imbalances.
Tim Besley was asked by the Queen why nobody had predicted the crisis. His reply to her on behalf of the British Academy can be found here.
Olivier Blanchard (chief economist at the IMF) gave a lecture which gives a good overview of causes and policy responses. The video of the lecture is here.
Saturday, 15 August 2009
More on the efficient markets hypothesis and modern macroeconomics
But the EMH, if you don’t take it too literally and get carried away about axiomatically defining strong, weak and other kinds of efficiency as though you were dealing with axiomatic quantum field theory, does recognize one true thing: that it’s #$&^ing difficult or well-nigh impossible to systematically predict what’s going to happen. You may think you know you’re in a bubble, but you still can’t tell whether things are going up or down the next day. The EMH was a kind of jiu-jitsu response on the part of economists to turn weakness into strength. “I can’t figure out how things work, so I’ll make that a principle.”
(This relates to my previous blog on what Lucas said.) Krugman agrees that the idea you can't predict the future is a rather weak scientific idea to turn into a principle. In fact he quotes an old piece by Jeff Frankel:
It used to be that the goal in econometric work was to get results that were statistically significant, to reject the null hypothesis. In order for an author to stand up in front of a conference proudly, or to expect to publish his paper in a journal, he or she sought to get significant results. This is difficult to do in macroeconomics. The world is a complicated place; it is unlikely that the few key variables that emerge from the particular theory that one has developed will actually go far toward explaining a real-world time series. So what we have done — quite cleverly — is to redefine the rules. Now the goal is to fail to reject the null hypothesis, to get results that are statistically insignificant — in essence, to find nothing. It is far easier to find nothing than to find something. Typically one fails to reject many hypotheses every day, even in the shower or on the way to work.
Sunday, 9 August 2009
Lucas defends economics
Bubbles and Behavioural Economics
Tuesday, 4 August 2009
Okun's Law - learn some economics
Monday, 27 July 2009
UK output falling fast

Monday, 20 July 2009
The state of economics
In my view, when you have Nobel Memorial Prize-caliber economists like Arizona State's Edward Prescott, Chicago's Robert Lucas and Eugene Fama, and Harvard's Robert Barro claiming that there are valid theoretical arguments proving that fiscal stimulus simply cannot work, not even in a deep depression--even though they cannot enunciate such theoretical arguments coherently--it is entirely fair for outsiders to conclude that academic economics as a profession is useless.
Friday, 17 July 2009
China bounces back

China's economy grew at an annual rate of 7.9% between April and June, up from 6.1% in the first quarter, thanks to the government's big stimulus package. The country's quickening economic expansion comes as most nations in the West continue to experience recession. Beijing now expects China to achieve 8% growth for 2009 as a whole, which compares with a predicted contraction of between 1% and 1.5% in the US. (BBC News; click figure to enlarge.)
Everyone seems surprised that the Chinese economy has recovered so quickly. This is being ascribed to the stimulus package announced in last November, but it is surprising that it could come through so quickly.
Thursday, 16 July 2009
Unemployment rising rapidly

Wednesday, 15 July 2009
The paradox of thrift — for real
Tuesday, 14 July 2009
UK Inflation falls (a little)
UK annual inflation fell in June as the Consumer Prices Index (CPI) dropped to 1.8% from 2.2% in May, the Office for National Statistics (ONS) said. This is below the Bank of England's target of 2%, but it is surprising perhaps that it is only now below target given general defaltion fears. This is the year on year rate, so measures price changes over the last 12 months, rather than how prices have changed just over the last month or so.
The Retail Prices Index (RPI), a key inflation figure which includes mortgage interest payments and housing costs, became even more negative, falling to -1.6% from -1.1%, the lowest figure since the statistic has been collected in 1948! However given that monetary policy has pushed interest rates down so much, this is perhaps not such a good measure of inflation.
See this page from the BBC for an explanation of inflation and how the statistics are calculated.
Monday, 13 July 2009
Markets and Morals

Inspiring Green Innovation
Sunday, 21 June 2009
Don't tighten policy yet!
Friday, 5 June 2009
1931 and all that

Miscellany from Krugman
Sunday, 26 April 2009
Lord Stern on Climate Change
Saturday, 18 April 2009
Irrationality, salad and chips - failure of the independence axiom
"Investigators asked college students to choose foods from menus that differed in only one feature; one menu offered a salad and the other did not. The point? To find out whether the presence of a salad on the menu influenced what else the students ate. It did. The students choose French fries more often from the menu with the salad."
Why do people like trams so much?
Wednesday, 8 April 2009

According to Eichengreen and O'Rourke: "globally we are tracking or doing even worse than the Great Depression, whether the metric is industrial production, exports or equity valuations." Krugman calls this "half a Great Depression" becuase the fall in manufacturing output in the US is not as bad as it was in 1929. But they point out that looking at global data, things don't look so good. On the bright side, the policy response (monetary and fiscal) looks a lot better now, so there is still hope...
Tuesday, 7 April 2009
Inflation not falling as fast as expected

Friday, 3 April 2009
More on the American bank plan to get rid of toxic assets
Wednesday, 25 March 2009
Gentlemen Prefer Blands; or it all depends on the elasticities.
My colleague Santi sets out a very interesting analysis. As any good economist will tell you, it all depends on the elasticities. If v (value of match) = pq, and p depends on q, then write p = p(q) (with p' < 0) so v = p(q)q. Then dv/dq = qp' + p is positive if p'q/p, the elasticity of breeding probability with respect to female quality, which we label as e, is greater than -1 (recall that p' < 0).
If e > -1 (e.g. if p is constant) then the higher quality is not offset by the reduction in probability, so we would still have positive assortative matching (PAM). If e < -1, we get negative matching (NAM); high quality men will want to avoid high quality women as they are too unlikely to have children.
But e may be variable. Suppose q lies between 0 and 1 and p = 1 - q. Then v = q-qq (I can't do squares in Html!); simple calculus, or graphing v against q, shows that the highest value women have q = 0.5 and the worst 0 or 1. Women can be ranked by the absolute value of (q-0.5), so q = 0.25 is as good as q = 0.75. Then we would see NAM between the highest quality women and a representative half of the men (of all types) and PAM between the lowest quality women and the other half of the men. More like 'Gentlemen prefer blands'.
With equal numbers of men and women, whether some agents remain unmatched depends on whether they have a 'reservation quality' (as in 'I'm not that desperate!'). In the set-up above, if men will not accept v less than v*, single men will be low quality, and single women will have q outside the interval bounded by the two solutions to q - qq = v*. So we would observe spinsters who are either successful professional women too busy to breed or women ready to breed but too uneducated; an interesting area for empirical research.
As Santi says, it is true that we have a lot to learn from other disciplines, but the concept of elasticity can also be useful outside economics. Note the resemblance between v = pq ,and revenue = pq = price x quantity. If a man has a cost per unit of quality of c of providing 'satisfaction' to a high quality woman then v = (p - c)q, which can be thought of as total revenue less total cost. So maybe there are further parallels to be explored.
Tuesday, 24 March 2009
Gentlemen Prefer Dumbs

Then my anthropologist friend M raised a question: We observe that males tend to go for females that are not more intelligent or successful than themselves. Why? After acknowledging that there was a certain truth in that, K and I looked for an answer. The simplistic model of matching that I proposed above assumes that females will have offspring for sure. But that may not be the case in reality. More successful and intelligent women will typically have better outside options to childbearing so they are less likely to agree to reproduce. So if that probability is Pi and the value of female's i offspring is Qi, the value of matching with that female is just PiQi. Hence when going for more intelligent females, men may be trading off higher quality offspring with a lower probability of reproduction. Notice that the same argument applies if Pi represents the men bargaining power within the household against female i and Qi is the quality of the relationship or a measure of some other type of investment made by the female. This assumption can be enough to generate a non-assortative matching in which men have a positive optimal level of female “dumbness." And implies, if we maintain the assumption of equal number of males and females, that that some very intelligent and successful females may remain unmatched.
The moral of the story for you should be that we can try to apply that economic thinking to shed light on any question, phenomenon or puzzle you may encounter. And also that we have lot to learn from listening to other disciplines. That is, unless you are too busy chasing a dumb enough partner out there.
Monday, 23 March 2009
US Banks
This plan will produce big gains for banks that didn’t actually need any help; it will, however, do little to reassure the public about banks that are seriously undercapitalized.
Thursday, 19 March 2009
Football: economists excel at games (in theory)


Everyone enjoyed themselves and the staff upheld the reputation of the School by winning 2-0. Santi and Ahmed were the goal-scorers.
Here's a short video of the game:
This year, we're going to draw the SH team members' names out of a hat during the coming SH party (Thursday 4th March - in the coffee room, 1st floor, 31 BP, 4pm) and the game itself will be towards the end of March. If you want to put your name forward for the team, just email Karen or Christina on Economics.SSO@ed.ac.uk and we'll put you on the list.
Tuesday, 17 March 2009
Feedback from the Credit Crunch Seminar 2
Take 60 ordinary people, roughly a cross-section of Edinburgh society, and invite them to give their views on the credit crunch and the economic crisis. Or rather, light the blue touch-paper and stand back, well back.
The meeting was permeated by a deep sense of injustice. How can people just walk away from the mess they have created, often with a big pension, when others lose their jobs and pensions though no fault of their own? You may think economics deals with efficiency and hard-headed analysis, and that concerns of equity and justice are the domain of the soft-headed disciplines (usually ending in 'ology'). Wrong for two reasons! Firstly, if people care about fairness then it will affect their behaviour. For example, they may avoid buying from businesses they see as treating their workers and suppliers badly, or not doing their bit for the environment. Or if people at work are treated fairly, they may be more productive. Secondly, think of the raw politics of the situation. You may disagree with knee-jerk reactions to punish greedy bankers, but if a political party can get support for measures to redress injustices, real or perceived, then - purely as a matter of economic forecasting - you need to take that on board in forming your expectations of future policy.