Monday, 21 December 2009
Paul Samuelson
The Great Depression motivated him to become an economist. The hardships of those turbulent times left a longlasting impression on him. He was economic advisor to John F. Kennedy and Lyndon B. Johnson. As a Neo-Keynesian, he always advocated the necessity of the intervention of the State in the operations of markets. Last year, just after the explosion of the financial crisis, he wrote "Farewell to Friedman-Hayek libertarian capitalism," an incendiary piece against the Bush administration, the free-market triumphalists and their theorists. Reading it is a good way to remember this giant and to preserve his legacy.
Wednesday, 16 December 2009
More Economics posters
Monday, 16 November 2009
"SuperFreakonomics" has some ideas for reëngineering the planet
According to Levitt and Dubner, the story’s message is a simple one: if, at any particular moment, things look bleak, it’s because people are seeing them the wrong way. “When the solution to a given problem doesn’t lie right before our eyes, it is easy to assume that no solution exists,” they write. “But history has shown again and again that such assumptions are wrong.” As usual, they say, the anxiety is unwarranted.
First, the globalwarming threat has been exaggerated; there is uncertainty about how, exactly, the earth will respond to rising CO2 levels, and uncertainty has “a nasty way of making us conjure up the very worst possibilities.”
Second, solutions are bound to present themselves: “Technological fixes are often far simpler, and therefore cheaper, than the doomsayers could have imagined."
Levitt and Dubner, reports the New Yorker, have in mind a very particular kind of “technological fix.” One scheme that Levitt and Dubner endorse features a fleet of fibreglass boats equipped with machines that would increase the cloud cover over the oceans. Another calls for constructing a vast network of tubes for sucking cold water from the depths of the sea to the surface. Far and away their favorite plan involves mimicking volcanoes.
To which New Yorker journalist, Elizabeth Kolbert responds:
To be skeptical of climate models and credulous about things like carbon-eating trees and cloudmaking machinery and hoses that shoot sulfur into the sky is to replace a faith in science with a belief in science fiction. This is the turn that “SuperFreakonomics” takes, even as its authors repeatedly extoll their hard-headedness. All of which goes to show that, while some forms of horseshit are no longer a problem, others will always be with us.
If you want to read more, go here: The New Yorker by Elizabeth Kolbert, Nov. 15, 2009.
Monday, 9 November 2009
Paying b*nkers
Why do "we" (need to) pay bankers so much?
Whether we wanted it or not, we taxpayers are now the de facto owners of some big banks in this country, because the government bought lots of their shares to rescue them from last year's financial crisis. Now many of us are angry: why on earth do "we" have to pay huge bonuses to those bank managers, who (at least partially) are responsible for the crisis in the first place? A lot of people find this unfair and immoral.
"Immoral" is perhaps too strong a word, but I do think paying them huge bonuses after the crisis they may well have caused is hardly moral, at least in the usual sense of the word. At the same time, however, I am inclined to think that the bonuses are inevitable, especially if we want to avoid further trouble in the financial sector and, much more importantly, the whole economy. Let me explain why.
It takes tremendous expertise to run contemporary financial institutions. We all know how complicated financial products are. Even as an academic economist, I get overwhelmed by the financial terminologies and technicalities involved in my little personal banking account. I have no idea how hard it would be to stay on top of the many big things a large bank does.
Some commentators and politicians say what banks should simplify what they offer, much like traditional high street banks. However, we should never forget that it is this major development in the financial sector over the last two decades that allowed the British economy to do better than many other developed economies. And needless to say, London and Edinburgh are the two British cities that benefited most from it. True, the bankers may not necessarily understand completely what they buy and sell (, which became apparent during the crisis), but still, there are very few people who have even the minimum knowledge and skills necessary to make sure things do not become worse than they were in 2008.
Here's the first dilemma: most or all genuine banking experts are people who were, at least to some extent, involved in the crisis. It may seem insane and immoral to hire those people again to run "our" banks. But moral issues aside, precisely because we are the de facto owners of these banks, we want the best people to do the job. In principle, we can install "clean" people from outwith the financial sector into the banks' managerial teams, but in practice, that is bound to be utterly disastrous. Again, because the expertise required to run banks is fairly peculiar and because there is so much at stake, we don't want novices in there.
But why pay them so much? Shouldn't they work hard for free, now that the government helped them out? Well, another dilemma is that competent bankers are still very expensive to hire. They may be in demand by other financial firms. Or, because they had already been very well paid, they could simply retire and live a quiet life if we offered them modest salaries (like mine). We are in a free society, so we cannot force good bankers to work for us (otherwise it's slavery). Instead, we have to induce them to want to work for us. That's why we need to pay them so well. The fact that bank managers get paid in large part by the bonuses is actually a good sign, because that means they get rewarded only when they have got things right.
It seems to me that we face an uncomfortable choice between being "moral" on bankers' pay and getting out of the current downturn as quickly as possible. Of course, it would be ideal if we could remain "moral" as we get out of this mess, but unfortunately, for the reasons I've discussed here, that seems rather unrealistic. It's really hard for us to agree on what's moral or fair, but insofar as most of us benefit from the recovery of the financial sector (especially in Edinburgh) and the whole economy, I'm not too bothered by how much the bankers get. The amount of the bonuses is tiny anyway, compared to what is at stake.
Tuesday, 3 November 2009
Mankiw on Obama's health care reform
If progressive taxes pay for the health system and federal health subsidies are smaller for families with higher incomes, the reform is effectively imposing a higher marginal tax rate on middle classes. Earning more means higher health costs for families. And that may disincentivise working harder. Mankiw does not critice the reform itself, but just want to make the point that the hardworking ethics that characterize the US (as opposed to the allegedly laziness of the Europeans) may be in danger. Of course, the trade-off is not that simple. Better health care also means a healthier population and more productive too. There are all sorts of positive externalities from an improved health system that Mankiw does not seem to factor in.
Saturday, 31 October 2009
Dinner & Drinks
Yesterday our fourth-year students and members of staff (Ahmed, Christina, Eirlys, Karen, Kohei, Santi, Simon, Stuart) went out for dinner at Imans, followed by drinks at a pub (or two?). We all had a GREAT time!! Special thanks to the students who organized such a lovely event.
Monday, 26 October 2009
Lehman and the Financial Crisis
Friday, 23 October 2009
Do you fancy working in trading?
So what is it like to work in trading?
BP is giving you an opportunity to find out by playing their online Trading Game, which is open to new registrations from 5 October. They say that the game will give you an insight into the dynamic and fast-paced world of commodity trading, where you will use their market analysis to trade live futures prices.
bptradinggame.com
Thursday, 22 October 2009
Morgan Stanley Presentation
Interested in studying abroad next year?
We're still working on the final list of universities that we'll allow you to go to but we plan to have it ready for that meeting.
Wednesday, 21 October 2009
Morgan Stanley give prizes to our Economics students
Morgan Stanley came to the School of Economics today and gave out certificates and Amazon vouchers to the three best performers in each of the first and second year Economics courses and over the whole of Junior and Senior Honours last year.
Here's a photo of our Head of School greeting the visitors - I'll post more photos tomorrow.
It's an ongoing thing - see the photo on the noticeboard behind them.
Friday, 16 October 2009
What follows is an Economics 1a blog (the Eco 1A blog site was disabled a while back)
I continue the intercourse I was having with Pietro during last Monday's lecture.
We both agreed on Berlusconi's eccentricities (euphemistically put) but what of his image as a tax cutting free marketeer? And I wonder what has actually happened to taxes in particular and the Italian economy in general over the last ten years?
The tax take as a % of GDP has varied little showing just a slight rise. In 2000 it was just over 40% and in 2008 stood at around 43%. Some of the rise came from fiscal drag which Italy has famously exploited in the past (fiscal drag is where personal tax allowances are not uprated to allow for inflation so that in real terms you start paying taxes at the basic rate of 23% at lower levels of earnings).
GDP growth per capita has been around about 0.5% and quite poor by historical standards.
Inflation has been steady at around 2.5% (yawn)
What about debt? Not good this one. The debt to GDP ratio has been hovering around the 100% mark this decade (and you thought the UK was bad!) but has grown alarmingly to nearly 110% recently because of the recession.
Unemployment? High by EU standards but falling through the noughties - in 2001 it was just over 9% and in 2008 just over 6%. Perhaps this is the one thing that has changed over the Berlusconi tenure.
But in terms of concrete macro policies what has been implemented?
Well not much - but that's Italy for you. Some Berlusconi policies such as the raising of the retirment age were reversed by Prodi in 06-07. Berlusconi did manage to ease labour market hiring and firing restrictions for new workers but we should be careful before we ascribe the fall in unemployment to this.
In the recent elections he promised to cut tax rates on labour by 1% per year each year (I presume for no more than 23 years!). But his latest fiscal plan commits to increase the tax burden on labour (as a % of earnings) not decrease it.
So what should he do now?
Would it be wise to cut labour taxes now? Well there could be justification for a short term "fiscal" boost on account of the recession (Simon Clark will be lecturing soon about government policy when aggregate demand gets stuck at too low a level to allow full employment) but as noted above debt to GDP is high and growing at an alarming rate. Interestingly even though Italy is in the Euro area - an area where supposedly all governments can borrow at a common interest rate - it is actually having to pay a third of a percent more on new debt issued than Germany does.
There could be long run and permanent effects to output from permanent labour tax cuts but in an economy where these rates are "so-so" the extent and existence of these effects have been difficult to establish.
It might be argued therefore that tax cuts now will generate debtas later. We would be transferring income from future generations to the current one. Given the projections for pensions for future generations compared with the current cohort I am not so sure this would be fair. Then again as the economy grows, future generations do tend to be better off than current ones. Whatever you do on taxes you have to keep an eye on that potentially spiralling debt.
To sum up, I think there have been very few changes in economy policy brought into effect in Italy over the last ten years. Perhaps in the context of Italian politics the best thing a politician can do for his/her country is nothing!
Thursday, 15 October 2009
New IMF Blog
Wednesday, 14 October 2009
Have they lost the plot? What should be the mandate of the Nobel Committee?
Computer software for .ac.uk users
Go to http://www.microsoft.com/uk/education/studentoffer/default.aspx
Please note that we are not promoting Micro$oft here, merely letting you know that this deal is available to .ac.uk email account holders - other operating systems are available: BSD, Darwin (Mac OS X), Linux, SunOS (Solaris/OpenSolaris).
Tuesday, 13 October 2009
Mugshots of Economics at Edinburgh
They're available from the Economics UG Office for £4.
Hoodies and Tshirts are coming soon...
Monday, 12 October 2009
GES Sandwich Student Placements
These placements are for a full year and would mean that you have to apply for (and be granted) a year out between third and fourth year, but we would support your request for this to College. They are also very competitive so you need to be confident of getting a 2:1 or a 1st to even consider applying.
The GES run a Summer Placement scheme too - further info about summer 2010 placements is due to become available in December and we'll publish the information when we receive it.
The opening date for this round of applications is Friday 9 October, and the closing date for receipt of applications is Friday 16 October 2009.
Our contact has said that he is willing to help with advice on how to prepare, either on the economics or general competency side. He'll email you some hints on interview structure and success. Let me know if you want to take him up on this and I'll forward your email onto him (Economics.SSO@ed.ac.uk).
http://www.civilservice.gov.uk/networks/professional/ges/students/ssp.aspx
Thursday, 8 October 2009
Selfish basterds: On rationality in Economics (II)
I think that the main reason for this is that they are confounding an assumption with an ontological proposition about human nature. Economists do not postulate that people are always rational. Nor that humans are only selfish or materialistic or care only about money. In this post I would like to clarify that rationality is just that, an assumption. In the next one, I will explain why it is not as stupid as journalists relish so much to say.
In "The Methodology of Positive Economics," the leading chapter of Essays in Positive Economics (1953), Milton Friedman argued that it is not important whether humans are actually rational or not. What is important is whether they behave like rational beings, so the rationality assumption can be used fruitfully to explain behaviour. He made the analogy with the study of how leaves locate in the branches of trees. The tree may not truly grow them to maximize exposure to sunlight, but if they behave as if it did, then it is a powerful assumption to make in our study of trees. That is the principle that should guide us in the use of the rationality assumption.
It is true that sometimes economists have jumped into the void of wishful thinking, and postulated that human nature (in case such a thing exists) corresponds to the one of a rational, narrowly-minded, materialistic being. Many market-triumphalists have done that (not Friedman, interestingly enough), and policy prescriptions sometimes have suffered from an abuse of rationality, and more specifically of narow self-interest (they are not the same as we will see next time) as a fundamental belief and not as an approximation to reality. That is precisely why that girl that I mentioned in my previous post in this series thought that Economics was hideous; or why journalists, like Adam Curtis, like to portray economists (and economics students, by extension) as sociopaths. But what should concern us is that any economist willing to make the leap from assumption to beliefs is doomed to do wrong and potentially dangerous economic analysis.
What good economists think is that the assumption of rationality can be a very powerful tool in explaining behaviour. It is a simplification, of course, but without simplifications, no theory has any explanatory power. In that respect, I would like to mention a short story by the Argentinian writer Jorge Luis Borges (in the photo above). In On Rigour in Science, Borges told the story of an empire, whose scientists, after generations, build a map of the kingdom in 1:1 scale. The map was a totally accurate description of reality. But what would be the use of such a map? Absolutely none. The assumption of rationality, Economics in itself, is a map of human and social phenomena. There may be some maps better than others, and we should strive to improve the ones we have, but without them, we will certainly get lost.
Monday, 5 October 2009
The Love Of Money
The middle part of the programme, "The Age of Risk", does a much better job at uncovering the causes of the financial meltdown we experienced a year ago. According to it, its main culprit was Alan Greenspan. In the documentary, his career from just an unknown economists to head of the Federal Reserve is paralleled to the rise of the belief on self-regulating markets. The last five minutes of the programme are especially revealing. There, a tired and defeated Greenspan confesses that he still does not understand what went wrong. His surprise and disbelief is, at the same time, very telling, and very moving. It is probably the highlight of this interesting programme.
The website for the programme is here. You can watch each individual episode just by clicking on the links above. And then answer, is Greenspan to blame?
Thursday, 1 October 2009
Sunday, 27 September 2009
Intermezzo: Writing about economics in another (more exotic?) language
It was a challenging but interesting experience. I am a native speaker of Japanese (and highly non-native speaker of English as some of you may know) so in principle it should be easier for me to write in Japanese. But I found it really hard. I think there are two reasons for it. The first is that I didn't know much of the Japanese economics jargon because my serious economics training was almost all in English. The second, which is related but much more serious, is that there are no Japanese translations for many terms in the first place. Let me give two (of many) examples.
To begin with, a half of what I wrote was about (the game theoretic analysis of) "cheap talk" but even now I still don't know how to translate it. Because it's a short phrase, I spelled the English pronunciation with Japanese characters like "chiipu toku", and fortunately the column editor liked the sound. It may well have been the very first time the term "chiipu toku" ever appeared in Japanese mass media.
The other half was about "verifiable disclosure", but again no translation for this term seemed to exist. It would be too long and awkward if I spelled the sound, so I really had to come up with a translation. There is a nice established Japanese translation for "disclosure" but there are a few equally good candidates for the word "verifiable" in that context. So I chose one that sounded best to myself. If my translation of "verifiable disclosure" becomes commonly used in Japan (at least among academics), then I should get credit for it!
Wednesday, 23 September 2009
How/If Economists Got the Crisis All Wrong
On September 2, 2009 PAUL KRUGMAN in an article How Did Economists Get It So Wrong? wrote:
"It’s hard to believe now, but not long ago economists were congratulating themselves over the success of their field. Those successes — or so they believed — were both theoretical and practical, leading to a golden era for the profession... Last year, everything came apart. Few economists saw our current crisis coming, but this predictive failure was the least of the field’s problems. More important was the profession’s blindness to the very possibility of catastrophic failures in a market economy."
Krugman then goes on to answer "What happened to the economics profession? And where does it go from here?" questions, and concludes that
"It’s much harder to say where the economics profession goes from here. But what’s almost certain is that economists will have to learn to live with messiness. That is, they will have to acknowledge the importance of irrational and often unpredictable behavior, face up to the often idiosyncratic imperfections of markets and accept that an elegant economic “theory of everything” is a long way off. In practical terms, this will translate into more cautious policy advice — and a reduced willingness to dismantle economic safeguards in the faith that markets will solve all problems." (to read more click here)
John Cochrane responded to Paul Krugman's accusations on September 11th, 2009 saying that
"Paul Krugman has no interesting ideas whatsoever about what caused our current financial and economic problems, what policies might have prevented it, or what might help us in the future, and he has no contact with people who do. “Irrationality” and “spend like a drunken sailor” are pretty superficial compared to all the fascinating things economists are writing about it these days."he goes on to say:
"Again, what is the alternative? Does Krugman really think we can make progress on his – and my – agenda for economic and financial research — understanding frictions, imperfect markets, complex human behavior, institutional rigidities – by reverting to a literary style of exposition, and abandoning the attempt to compare theories quantitatively against data? Against the worldwide tide of quantification in all fields of human endeavor (read “Moneyball”) is there any real hope that this will work in economics?
No, the problem is that we don’t have enough math. Math in economics serves to keep the logic straight, to make sure that the “then” really does follow the “if,” which it so frequently does not if you just write prose. The challenge is how hard it is to write down explicit artificial economies with these ingredients, actually solve them, in order to see what makes them tick. Frictions are just bloody hard with the mathematical tools we have now." if you wan to read more click here.
Tuesday, 22 September 2009
Selfish basterds: On rationality in Economics (I)
In my MSc dissertation, I worked with a model of coalition formation in which individuals differed in resources and abilities and could get together in order to produce output. Over and over again, I found that in the equilibrium of that model the more able agents formed groups with other able agents and that the group structure was ordered in that way. I say that I got that result over and over again because I found it outrageous so I checked and rechecked my computations. I did not like the fact that MY model yielded a hierarchical world in which people ended up merging with people similar to them and the less able and less rich got excluded. The fact was that I was letting my personal ideas obscure my economic thinking.
A few years later, I was a recently appointed lecturer at the University of Edinburgh and I was about to run my first economic experiment. As part of the process, I had to find subjects. I resorted to traditional methods like posters, showing up at the beginnning of lectures and distributing flyers across George Square. Students mostly liked the idea of being paid £10 for an hour of their time so the experience of chatting them up was pleasant. However, I remember vividly the visceral reaction of one female student. When I told her that we were looking for people to participate in research in Economics she answered "I hate Economics, I don't want to have anything to do with it. It's hideous."
Since last year, I have taught game theory on the MSc on Carbon Management that we run jointly with the Business School and Geosciences. I performed a simple classroom experiment in which students in the course played a public good game. They had to decide whether to contribute towards a public fund or not. Individual payoffs (I actually paid them in cash) increase with the number of contributors if you contribute too, but they increase even faster if you remain out. In equilibrium everybody should free-ride. Most students were shocked to find that, indeed, very few of them contributed. They thought that the world, and even themselves, was different. But once they felt the power of incentives, they were the first ones in leaving moral self-images aside.
Last Spring, I gave a workshop on economic experiments to students interested in the topic. I reported one experiment ("The Competitive Advantage of Sanctioning Institutions," O. Gürerk, B. Irlenbusch and B. Rockenbach, Science, 2006), in which subjects had to choose whether to play the game above or another version in which after contributions decisions are made, they could punish others at a cost. As you can expect, contributions are typically much higher in the latter case. I asked the audience which game they thought that subjects selected more often in the first round of the experiment. They all answered "the one with punishments". They were dismayed to find that it was actually in the other way around and that contributions were very low. I asked one student why she answered in the way she did. She replied "because that is how I would like the world to be, a world where people are nice".
So the moral of this first post is the following: Don't let your good feelings mix up with your Economics. Otherwise you will not be doing a good service to yourself nor to the world.
Only if you are ready to abandon your prejudices and your self-image as a saint, then you can continue reading.
Friday, 18 September 2009
Gary Becker speaks up for the Chicago School
- The crisis occurred because economists still do not understand financial instruments well enough. In other words, Economics as a science is not advanced enough to deal with such issues, pretty much in the same way as medieval medicine was not ready to fight viruses or used leeches to cure diseases.
- The regulated know much better what to do than the regulator. The crisis should be solved by economic agents and not by the state because, paraphrasing Churchill's dictum on democracy, free markets are the worst economic system, except for all those other forms that have been tried from time to time.
You can watch the video here.
What do you think?
Wednesday, 16 September 2009
Monday, 14 September 2009
Who guards the investors?
In The Republic, Plato required his king-philosopher to have neither material possessions nor a family that he could favour. He also trusted law enforcement to a caste of guards. He was thus very aware of the problem of incentives. He also confronted the natural question that such idea begged, an idea that Alan Moore explored centuries later in his graphic novel Watchmen: Quis custodiet ipsos custodes? Who would guard the guards? Plato’s answer was that it was necessary that the guards should be highly moral and spirited individuals, able to look beyond their own material interests and able to sacrifice for their fellow citizens (compare that to
To a large extent, this dichotomy in Plato’s thinking reflects the two types of proposals made after the recent financial crisis: On the one hand, measures aimed at improving regulations and constructing better incentive schemes and, on the other hand, the calls to a more moral approach to business, to an ethical regeneration of the economic sphere, that allegedly would ameliorate the rampant greed that reigns in international markets.
But unless human nature had changed dramatically in the last two hundred years, I am afraid that these calls to a moral renaissance will be empty. In his wonderful book The Passions and The Interests, Albert O. Hirschman showed how capitalism, and thus greed, emerged precisely from the total failure of traditional moral systems, of those ethical principles based on religion or a shared national destiny; a failure that precipitated the religious and nationalist conflicts of the XVI and XVII centuries. As a solution, Adam Smith wanted to design a “theology without God”, whose centre would be occupied by a governing principle that humans would feel naturally inclined to follow without any appeal to supernatural powers. That force was self-interest. That force was greed. To illustrate this I will use the example I always give to my students: suppose you are a person that belongs to an ethnic or religious minority. You are walking down the street and suddenly a bunch of people from a rival ethnic or religious group start chasing you with very threatening intentions. If suddenly you started throwing £20 notes behind you, this people would immediately stop chasing your and start collecting the bank notes. Self-interest is a very powerful force, capable of overriding other forces of moral or ethical nature.
All this suggests that moral calls to businessmen, investors and bankers will prove useless. The stakes are so big, there is so much money to be made in international financial markets that there will be always someone ready to bend these principles. At the same time, regulation has proved ineffective in preventing these behaviours or at least that these behaviours meet monetary success. The only way out of this catch-22 situation is to acknowledge -the sooner the better- that the game between the regulator and the economic agents is a rat race, a fight in which the beast of self-interest that Adam Smith unleashed will always look for ways to break the chains that Leviathan wants to put on it.
Sunday, 6 September 2009
More reflections on the state of economics
Friday, 4 September 2009
Cricket stats
Almost all commentators regarded Australia's target of 546 to win in their second innings as virtually impossible to achieve. The argument is simply that the previous highest winning total in the fourth innings was 418 (W.Indies vs Australia in 2003). However I believe this is largely a statistical artifact. To register a high winning fourth innings score certain things must hold simultaneously. First, obviously, the target must be big. Secondly, there must be enough time to get the runs. I strongly suspect that the conjunction of these two events is pretty rare (especially when the target is set by the other side, who arguably should not set gettable targets).
It would be interesting to know how many times there has been a target of say over 500 and more than two days left to play (as we just had at the Oval). Confirmation that this is unusual comes from looking at highest fourth innings totals: 17 of the highest 30 in test cricket have occurred since 2000 (8 of these since 2008). Until recently teams scored at a much lower rate than we see these days---there simply wasn't time in a 5 day game to be set a huge target within 3 days if teams score at say 250 a day (when there was no time limit England got to 654 for 5 in Durban before they had to catch a boat back home). Technology and the one-day game seem to have increased scoring rates, so 350 in a day is not unusual. So it is not surprising that few large scores were posted until recently. The point is that at the oval, there was plenty of time and the wicket wasn't that bad. I don't think the records were very relevant. Ricky Ponting made it clear afterwards that he and Mike Hussey were having no problems batting. Arguably it was only the two crucial runouts that turned the game.
Thursday, 27 August 2009
Market failures vs government failures
In the second part of his address, Stern argued that only a broad and encompassing effort by economists would be able to respond to the two main challenges the world faces today: Climate change and the alleviation of poverty, two goals that, he added, must be tackled jointly. Stern argued that we already own some of the necessary tools to do this. We, economists, just simply forgot them. He added that nevertheless these are just starting points (pigouvian taxes on externalities would not be enough to do the trick) and that the new advances on behavioral economics, institutional economics and theories of justice were the lines to follow.
Some of the final points made by Stern were slightly more vague. He argued that discussion and deliberation are necessary to achieve these objectives. These procedures are of paramount importance if we want a complete shift in preferences and views on individual responsability, in the same way in which decades ago society decided through public debate that driving under the influence of alcohol should be sanctioned. In the meantime, the Economics profession should enlighten such debate with new research primarily focused on market failures rather than on government misdeeds.
You can watch the lecture in full here.
Tuesday, 25 August 2009
Immoral safety?
But there are some situations where the economy is organised so that too little risk is taken. Suppose you have responsibility in an organisation for health and safety, or avoiding accusations of discrimination. If you are judged just on these criteria, and if you can impose regulations on those in the organisation who produce the final product, then why not impose the tightest regulations possible. This will maximise those indicators on which you are judged (e.g. no accidents, or no lawsuits).
But if you try to get rid of all downside risk, there can be no upside benefit. No risks are taken and the organisation stagnates. You see this in some schools, where teachers avoid activities that may involve some risk to children. But then the children will not get the benefits of those activities.
This is a form of moral hazard, perhaps better called immoral safety.
Monday, 24 August 2009
Credit Crunch reading
This youtube video.
At Brown University, there was a "conversation" between Peter Howitt, David Weil and Ross Levine, who discussed the economic situation, the bailout, and the outlook for the future (with paerticular reference to the US). Here's the video, and a short description in the Brown student newspaper.
Robert Skidelsky's recent review in the New York Review of Books of Martin Wolf's book. This is a thoughtful review bringing in nicely the role played by the global imbalances.
Tim Besley was asked by the Queen why nobody had predicted the crisis. His reply to her on behalf of the British Academy can be found here.
Olivier Blanchard (chief economist at the IMF) gave a lecture which gives a good overview of causes and policy responses. The video of the lecture is here.
Saturday, 15 August 2009
More on the efficient markets hypothesis and modern macroeconomics
But the EMH, if you don’t take it too literally and get carried away about axiomatically defining strong, weak and other kinds of efficiency as though you were dealing with axiomatic quantum field theory, does recognize one true thing: that it’s #$&^ing difficult or well-nigh impossible to systematically predict what’s going to happen. You may think you know you’re in a bubble, but you still can’t tell whether things are going up or down the next day. The EMH was a kind of jiu-jitsu response on the part of economists to turn weakness into strength. “I can’t figure out how things work, so I’ll make that a principle.”
(This relates to my previous blog on what Lucas said.) Krugman agrees that the idea you can't predict the future is a rather weak scientific idea to turn into a principle. In fact he quotes an old piece by Jeff Frankel:
It used to be that the goal in econometric work was to get results that were statistically significant, to reject the null hypothesis. In order for an author to stand up in front of a conference proudly, or to expect to publish his paper in a journal, he or she sought to get significant results. This is difficult to do in macroeconomics. The world is a complicated place; it is unlikely that the few key variables that emerge from the particular theory that one has developed will actually go far toward explaining a real-world time series. So what we have done — quite cleverly — is to redefine the rules. Now the goal is to fail to reject the null hypothesis, to get results that are statistically insignificant — in essence, to find nothing. It is far easier to find nothing than to find something. Typically one fails to reject many hypotheses every day, even in the shower or on the way to work.
Sunday, 9 August 2009
Lucas defends economics
Bubbles and Behavioural Economics
Tuesday, 4 August 2009
Okun's Law - learn some economics
Monday, 27 July 2009
UK output falling fast
Monday, 20 July 2009
The state of economics
In my view, when you have Nobel Memorial Prize-caliber economists like Arizona State's Edward Prescott, Chicago's Robert Lucas and Eugene Fama, and Harvard's Robert Barro claiming that there are valid theoretical arguments proving that fiscal stimulus simply cannot work, not even in a deep depression--even though they cannot enunciate such theoretical arguments coherently--it is entirely fair for outsiders to conclude that academic economics as a profession is useless.
Friday, 17 July 2009
China bounces back
China's economy grew at an annual rate of 7.9% between April and June, up from 6.1% in the first quarter, thanks to the government's big stimulus package. The country's quickening economic expansion comes as most nations in the West continue to experience recession. Beijing now expects China to achieve 8% growth for 2009 as a whole, which compares with a predicted contraction of between 1% and 1.5% in the US. (BBC News; click figure to enlarge.)
Everyone seems surprised that the Chinese economy has recovered so quickly. This is being ascribed to the stimulus package announced in last November, but it is surprising that it could come through so quickly.
Thursday, 16 July 2009
Unemployment rising rapidly
Wednesday, 15 July 2009
The paradox of thrift — for real
Tuesday, 14 July 2009
UK Inflation falls (a little)
UK annual inflation fell in June as the Consumer Prices Index (CPI) dropped to 1.8% from 2.2% in May, the Office for National Statistics (ONS) said. This is below the Bank of England's target of 2%, but it is surprising perhaps that it is only now below target given general defaltion fears. This is the year on year rate, so measures price changes over the last 12 months, rather than how prices have changed just over the last month or so.
The Retail Prices Index (RPI), a key inflation figure which includes mortgage interest payments and housing costs, became even more negative, falling to -1.6% from -1.1%, the lowest figure since the statistic has been collected in 1948! However given that monetary policy has pushed interest rates down so much, this is perhaps not such a good measure of inflation.
See this page from the BBC for an explanation of inflation and how the statistics are calculated.
Monday, 13 July 2009
Markets and Morals
Inspiring Green Innovation
Sunday, 21 June 2009
Don't tighten policy yet!
Friday, 5 June 2009
1931 and all that
Miscellany from Krugman
Sunday, 26 April 2009
Lord Stern on Climate Change
Saturday, 18 April 2009
Irrationality, salad and chips - failure of the independence axiom
"Investigators asked college students to choose foods from menus that differed in only one feature; one menu offered a salad and the other did not. The point? To find out whether the presence of a salad on the menu influenced what else the students ate. It did. The students choose French fries more often from the menu with the salad."
Why do people like trams so much?
Wednesday, 8 April 2009
According to Eichengreen and O'Rourke: "globally we are tracking or doing even worse than the Great Depression, whether the metric is industrial production, exports or equity valuations." Krugman calls this "half a Great Depression" becuase the fall in manufacturing output in the US is not as bad as it was in 1929. But they point out that looking at global data, things don't look so good. On the bright side, the policy response (monetary and fiscal) looks a lot better now, so there is still hope...
Tuesday, 7 April 2009
Inflation not falling as fast as expected
Friday, 3 April 2009
More on the American bank plan to get rid of toxic assets
Wednesday, 25 March 2009
Gentlemen Prefer Blands; or it all depends on the elasticities.
My colleague Santi sets out a very interesting analysis. As any good economist will tell you, it all depends on the elasticities. If v (value of match) = pq, and p depends on q, then write p = p(q) (with p' < 0) so v = p(q)q. Then dv/dq = qp' + p is positive if p'q/p, the elasticity of breeding probability with respect to female quality, which we label as e, is greater than -1 (recall that p' < 0).
If e > -1 (e.g. if p is constant) then the higher quality is not offset by the reduction in probability, so we would still have positive assortative matching (PAM). If e < -1, we get negative matching (NAM); high quality men will want to avoid high quality women as they are too unlikely to have children.
But e may be variable. Suppose q lies between 0 and 1 and p = 1 - q. Then v = q-qq (I can't do squares in Html!); simple calculus, or graphing v against q, shows that the highest value women have q = 0.5 and the worst 0 or 1. Women can be ranked by the absolute value of (q-0.5), so q = 0.25 is as good as q = 0.75. Then we would see NAM between the highest quality women and a representative half of the men (of all types) and PAM between the lowest quality women and the other half of the men. More like 'Gentlemen prefer blands'.
With equal numbers of men and women, whether some agents remain unmatched depends on whether they have a 'reservation quality' (as in 'I'm not that desperate!'). In the set-up above, if men will not accept v less than v*, single men will be low quality, and single women will have q outside the interval bounded by the two solutions to q - qq = v*. So we would observe spinsters who are either successful professional women too busy to breed or women ready to breed but too uneducated; an interesting area for empirical research.
As Santi says, it is true that we have a lot to learn from other disciplines, but the concept of elasticity can also be useful outside economics. Note the resemblance between v = pq ,and revenue = pq = price x quantity. If a man has a cost per unit of quality of c of providing 'satisfaction' to a high quality woman then v = (p - c)q, which can be thought of as total revenue less total cost. So maybe there are further parallels to be explored.